Two Interest Rates
Prior to 2008, commercial banks held reserves to meet a minimum required ratio of reserves to deposits. This ratio, the required reserve ratio, was mandated by the Fed and changed occasionally. In the period from the end of WWII up through 2008, banks held exactly this amount and excess reserves were equal to zero.
In October of 2008, the Fed began to pay interest on the reserves of commercial banks held at the Fed. Figure 1, copied from the San Francisco Fed website, shows that, once that change in policy was enacted, the excess reserves of commercial banks increased from zero, before 2008, to approximately $1.6 trillion in 2012. They are currently even higher at $2.2 trillion in 2016.
Prior to 2008, excess reserves were costly for commercial banks to hold because a commercial bank can make profits by lending reserves to private companies or to households or by purchasing interest bearing government securities. When three month T-bills pay positive interest, but reserves do not, a commercial bank will choose to hold zero excess reserves. After 2008, reserves held by commercial banks with the Fed are, to a first approximation, perfect substitutes for short term Treasury bills.
The post-2008 monetary environment is very different from the pre 2008 monetary environment. In the immortal words of Dorothy from the Wizard of Oz, “We’re not in Kansas anymore”. In the brave new technicolor world, the Fed controls two money interest rates, not one; the interest rate on reserves held at the Fed (IOR), and the Federal Funds Rate (FFR). By raising the IOR and the FFR at the same time, the Fed can engineer an increase in nominal rates without altering the opportunity cost of holding base money. By keeping the difference between the IOR and the FFR at zero, the Fed is allowing the private sector to create what Milton Friedman called, the optimal quantity of money.
Because money is costless to create, from a social perspective, Friedman argued that society should set the opportunity cost of holding money equal to zero. That is precisely what happens when the IOR equals the FFR. Because the demand and supply of money are identically equal, a simultaneous increase in the FFR and the IOR will not lead to a contraction in the money supply.
The Real Effects of an Interest Rate Rise
Even if the opportunity cost of holding money is zero, a positive interest rate surprise may still reduce the money value of expenditures on goods and services as the values of existing dollar-denominated income flows are revalued downwards. This revaluation will not only affect fixed income dollar valued securities, it will also affect indexed bonds and corporate equities. The magnitude of that effect will depend on the public perceptions of future inflation.
In the past, we have observed a negative correlation between unanticipated increases in the money interest rate, and real GDP. In 1979, the Volcker Fed engineered a big increase in the interest rate in order to bring inflation under control. It worked, and over the following decade, inflation fell. But the interest rate increase triggered one of the largest post-war recessions in US history. The $64 trillion question is: can the Fed engineer a rate rise without triggering a recession? The answer to that question is yes.
New Keynesians believe that prices and wages were slow to adjust because of so called ‘menu costs’. They incorporate that belief into their models with an equation that goes by the name of the ‘New-Keynesian Phillips Curve’. There is increasing evidence (Klenow and Malin) that menu costs are not large enough to explain the real effects of a monetary contraction and there is increasing evidence that there never was a Phillips curve in the sense in which the New-Keynesians need there to be one.
It is not prices that are sticky: it is expectations. The New-Keynesians are right to assert that the output gap and the unemployment rate are determined by ‘aggregate demand’. Aggregate demand depends on the beliefs of asset market participants about the future value of wealth and beliefs are self-fulfilling prophecies that depend on the ‘animal spirits’ of investors. We need a way for the Fed to intervene in the asset markets to stabilize asset prices and to prevent spillovers from volatile shifts in beliefs to the real economy.
One way to achieve that intervention would be to give the Fed the authority to trade in the stock market, as does the Bank of Japan. As I argued here, the Open Market Committee of the Fed should use that authority to actively trade an exchange traded fund in order to offset any potential drop in asset values that follows an interest rate increase. If unemployment is above target, the Fed would announce an increase in the growth path of the price of the ETF. If it were below target, they would announce a reduction in the growth path.
Why do I believe this would be effective? After all, conventional New-Keynesian wisdom holds that there is little or no connection between the value of the stock market and subsequent real economic activity. Conventional wisdom is wrong. Although there is little or no connections between short-run stock market fluctuations, I have shown in published empirical papers (2012,2015) that there is a strong and stable connection between persistent changes in the value of the stock market and changes in the unemployment rate. And I have shown in published theory papers, (2012,2013) why this chain is causal. When we feel wealthy, we are wealthy!
You can read more about these ideas in my book Prosperity for All, available for purchase on October 7th.